Tracking Number: 379396Title: "The Political Economy of Nuclear Restraint." The author observes that a government interested in greater freedom tends to oppose nuclear weapons programs both because this position tends to encourage international trade, aid, technology and investment, and because of potential reductions in government regulations and bloated budgets related to nuclear weapons progress. (950213)
Author: SOLINGEN, ETEL
Source: INTERNATIONAL SECURITY (PERIODICAL), FALL 1994, PP 126-159
Date: 19950213Text:
*FAR10802/13/95
Global Issues in Transition, No. 12
THE POLITICAL ECONOMY OF NUCLEAR RESTRAINT By Etel Solingen
SUMMARY: In countries sitting on the fence between nonproliferation and development of nuclear weapons, ruling coalitions pursuing economic liberalization are more likely to embrace regional nuclear regimes than are inward-looking, nationalist and radical-confessional coalitions. A review of developments on the Korean Peninsula, in South Asia, in the Middle East, and in Latin America provides impressive empirical support for this proposition. Liberalizing coalitions tend to oppose nuclear weapons programs both because of the favorable impact of this stance on efforts to garner international trade, aid, technology and investment, and because of potential reduction in government regulations and bloated budgets related to nuclear weapons programs. (Length: 14,400 words.)
Etel Solingen is Assistant Professor of Political Science at the University of California, Irvine, and a FAculty Fellow of the Institute on Global Conflict and Cooperation. She is the author of Industrial Policy, Technology, and International Bargaining: Designing Nuclear Industries in Argentina and Brazil (forthcoming) and editor of Scientists and the State: Domestic Structures and the International Context (1994). Her most recent research in international relationstheory has appeared in International Organization, Comparative Politics, International Studies Quarterly, and International Security. For their helpful comments, the author wishes to thank Harry Eckstein, Ted Hopf, Miles Kahler, Robert R. Kaufman, Timur Kuran, Stephen Krasner, Peter Lavoy, Pat Morgan, Kongdan Oh, Mark Petracca, Jim Ray, Richard Rosecrance, Wayne Sandholtz, Susan Shirk, Jack Snyder, Dorothy Solinger, Jessica Stern, Alec Stone, and two anonymous reviewers for International Security. Fuller documentation of the arguments presented herein appeared with the original text in International Security.
COPYRIGHT: This article has been cleared for republication in English and in translation by USIS and the press outside the United States. Credit to the author and the following note must appear on the title page of any reprint: Reprinted in abridged form from International Security, Fall 1994, pp. 126-59, by permission of the MIT Press, Cambridge, Massachusetts and the President and Fellows of Harvard College. Copyright (c) 1994 by the President and Fellows of Harvard College and the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. The article may not be further abridged without the express consent of Professor Solingen.
THE CHOICE by second-tier or would-be nuclear powers between establishing a regional nuclear nonproliferation regime and maintaining an ambiguous nuclear status is at the heart of debates about global security in the aftermath of the Cold War era.1/ The study of nuclear postures of regional powers (beyond the original five nuclear states) in the last three decades has traditionally emphasized their external-security concerns. Such emphasis provided a powerful tool to explain the pursuit of a nuclear deterrent by countries like South Korea, Israel and Taiwan, on the basis of legitimate existential fears. However, while their security concerns have been more or less constant for more than 30 years, these countries' nuclear postures in a number of cases have shifted over time. The external-security context in and of itself is not enough, therefore, to advance our knowledge about why these states embraced different instruments, at different times, for coping with such fears.
More recently, the notion that the democratic nature of states explains their reluctance to wage wars against their democratic brethren (but not against others) has become central to theoretical endeavors in international relations theory. Although the explosion of studies on the relationship between liberal democracy and peace has not yet included a systematic extension to the study of nonproliferation, it is often asserted that democratization will have a benign effect on denuclearization.
However, this apparent connection may be less solid than we might like to expect: I argue that examining the economic component of domestic liberalization in the different regional contexts may bring us closer to identifying an important engine creating nonproliferation regimes. In particular, ruling coalitions pursuing economic liberalization seem more likely to embrace regional nuclear regimes than their inward-looking, nationalist, radical-confessional counterparts.2/
I do not suggest that security considerations are irrelevant to nuclear postures. Rather, I suggest an interpretation for why different states choose -- over time -- different portfolios to cope with their respective security concerns. My emphasis is more on explaining a favorable disposition to enter regime-like arrangements in nuclear matters than on listing incentives to procure nuclear weapons, as in the classical tradition of nonproliferation scholarship. Moreover, my argument is only relevant to would-be or second-tier nuclear powers -- "fence-sitters" -- whose choices have taken place at a different world-time than that of the great powers.3/ Finally, although I refer to nuclear-weapons-free-zones (NWFZ) as the ultimate form of a regional nuclear regime, there may be other institutional arrangements short of such regimes that might help avoid the dangers of nuclearization.
COMPETING PERSPECTIVES ON THE SOURCES OF FENCE-SITTING
Neorealism and liberal-democratic theories of peace provide two alternate ways of viewing the choices made by would-be nuclear powers. Each approach has its strengths and its weaknesses.
Neorealism. The point of departure of neorealist perspectives is that in an anarchic world, states strive through self-help to increase their power relative to that of other states -- in a zero-sum context -- to secure their survival. This structure compels states to secure a balance-of-power equilibrium, and nuclear weapons can do the job by increasing security for all, and by generating caution, rough equality, and a clarity of relative power. Regimes, in this view, are anomalies of international life, and their occurrence ought not to be expected anyway. Where they emerge, they are no more than an epiphenomenon of deeper forces in world politics, that is, of power distribution. Prima facie, this perspective provides an intuitive entry into the kind of thinking that might have attracted many of these regional powers to the nuclear fence.4/
A general weakness of neorealism in explaining nuclear choices, however, resides in its inconclusiveness. States indeed hope to reduce their external vulnerability, yet under a given structure, such an objective leaves room for a wide range of means. A regional power with fears for its survival may opt for any of a number of different solutions to alleviate them, from a full-fledged declaration of nuclear capabilities to their total renunciation (to avoid escalation and instability, or to induce the other side to accept regional denuclearization). Consider, as an example of this variability of responses, India's test of a nuclear device and rejection of a regional nuclear regime; Israel's abstention from testing (but its warning that it would never be "second" in a regional nuclear race), while developing greater receptivity over time to a nuclear-weapons-free-zone (NWFZ); South Korea's, South Africa's, Egypt's and Taiwan's unilateral ratification and implementation of the Nuclear Non-proliferation Treaty (NPT), after tinkering with a weapons program; and Pakistan's new openness to NPT and NWFZ solutions after dedicated efforts to acquire a nuclear deterrent. Moreover, not only have different states chosen contrasting portfolios, but almost all have shifted their postures throughout the years. Taiwan, South Korea, Egypt and, more recently, South Africa, Brazil and Argentina each overturned an ambiguous nuclear status by entering international commitments for effective denuclearization. The "pursuit of security" simply does not tell us enough about differences across space nor about changes over time.
The extensive, mostly descriptive, literature on the choices of fence-sitters offers three main structural explanations of such differences. The first points to variance in vulnerability to massive conventional attacks. Thus, the more acutely vulnerable, such as Israel, Taiwan, South Korea, and (some have argued) South Africa, could be expected to be less likely to renounce a nuclear deterrent. However, the last three of these four countries have done precisely that.
A second explanation addresses the impact on its regional adversaries of one regional power's acquisition, or pursuit of, a nuclear option. However, the activities of a nuclear "pioneer" did not invariably lead to matching capabilities among adversaries. Egypt, South Korea, Taiwan (and even some African states) were suspected of harboring such designs to one degree or another, but in the end, all renounced that path.
A third explanation traces these differences or, more particularly, the decision to forgo a nuclear deterrent, to the willingness of a hegemon to provide fence-sitters with protection. Many analysts interpret the behavior of South Korea and Taiwan -- under U.S. tutelage -- in this light. But hegemonic protection does not seem to be either necessary or sufficient for a turnabout in nuclear postures. Such guarantees of protection played no role in the decisions of Egypt, Argentina, Brazil or South Africa to reverse ambiguous nuclear stances, while the security commitments of superpowers were insufficient to persuade North Korea, Iraq, Pakistan or Israel to effectively abandon nuclear weapons programs. Moreover, the U.S. commitment to Taiwan, said to have convinced the latter not to go nuclear, became questionable following Washington's normalization of relations with the People's Republic of China and the abrogation of the Washington-Taipei mutual security treaty.
In sum, the valuable insights we gain from a structural perspective are offset by its deficiencies. A state's structural context helps identify potential sources of nuclear postures, but does not account effectively for the great variation encountered across countries and throughout time. Diverse responses came about under comparable and quite stable regional security threats, and against a common global-historical background characterized by three constants: a bipolar world, unrelenting pressure from the respective hegemons (the United States and the Soviet Union) to eschew nuclear weapons, and a global normative structure squarely opposed to the horizontal proliferation of such weapons. Shifts in overt substantive postures and signals of internal differences over the virtues and costs of alternative nuclear paths suggest that, at the very least, the consequences of, and solutions to, similar security predicaments are not universally consistent. Exclusively structural analyses offer limited ground for inter-regional comparisons beyond general truisms, such as arguing that the security context is more fragile in the Middle East than in Latin America. But that reality did not prevent Brazil and Argentina from nurturing weapons capabilities for more than two decades. Indeed, two contrasting security contexts -- the Middle East and the Southern Cone -- had similar outcomes: regional powers embracing ambiguous nuclear postures and unwilling to commit to safeguarded denuclearization.
In the end, studies that focus exclusively on structural explanations either cast the argument in nonfalsifiable terms, or explain variation away through brief references to domestic considerations or to a rough-and-tumble bureaucratic-politics account. Yet, one cannot understand differences in hegemonic effectiveness without studying carefully the domestic political conditions that make certain states more receptive to external persuasion than others.5/
Liberal-democratic theories of cooperation. There is growing attention to domestic considerations, but mostly in the context of theories of "democratic peace" -- i.e., liberal democracies are not likely to wage wars amongst themselves, and why they are at least as likely as others to engage non-democratic partners in armed conflict. There has been no systematic attempt to extend these hypotheses to account for cooperative or non-cooperative behavior in the nuclear realm. What follows is an effort to (1) summarize, from the extant literature, a list of complementary institutional, perceptual and normative explanations of why democracies cooperate and (2) to expand these hypotheses to specify potential nuclear outcomes.
A first set of explanations relates the "democratic peace" to domestic legitimacy and accountability, to democracy's built-in institutional checks and balances, and to the basic norm of peaceful resolution of disputes. Following a Kantian conception of citizens' consent, the assumption is that the legitimacy granted by the domestic public of one liberal democracy to the elected representatives of another has a moderating effect away from violent solutions. Moreover, free speech, electoral cycles and the public policy process act as restraints on the ability of democratic leaders to pursue extreme policies toward fellow democracies. Similarly, the normative rejection of violent behavior at home is extended to cover citizens of other democracies.
How do we apply this reasoning to gauge the potential behavior of democratic dyads regarding nuclear weapons? One might extrapolate it to suggest that democratic dyads would be likely to shy away from basing their mutual security on nuclear weapons, which entail the most violent and extreme form of protection and some real measure of risk. Dyads in which a democracy faces a non-democratic rival can be expected to behave differently than a democratic dyad. Abhorrence of authoritarianism and its lack of popular accountability could encourage a democracy to undertake the risk of deterring non-democratic adversaries through nuclear weapons, as in Western deterrence strategy against the Warsaw Pact.6/ The fear that a non-democratic rival could hold a democracy hostage through nuclear threats might raise the threshold of tolerance for risk among citizens and leaders of that democracy. Where a democracy suspects an asymmetry in risk-aversion or propensity to go to war, it will arguably be more willing to contemplate extreme solutions, such as nuclear weapons, for its security predicament.
A second, related, set of explanations for the "democratic peace" points to the credibility, transparency and predictability of democratic systems. Democracies are respectful of the rule of law and appear to undertake more credible and durable commitments, which strengthens their reputation as predictable partners. Moreover, democracies are information-rich societies where knowledge about the internal evaluations of a policy or of the intensity of the preferences reinforces mutual credibility, enhancing the propensity to cooperate. One might expect that by minimizing fears of deception (which underlie classical prisoners' dilemmas), mutual credibility and transparency would strengthen the propensity of democratic dyads to accept mutual nuclear disarmament. In contrast, problems of uncertainty over ratification and implementation would be exacerbated for mixed or non-democratic dyads, because procedures cannot easily be followed. Stable democracies bind successive governments to international agreements, whereas non-democratic regimes might be replaced by challengers capable of reneging on international commitments to maintain legitimacy at home.7/
This seemingly reasonable, albeit speculative, extension of democratic theories of cooperation to explain the behavior of fence-sitters exposes problems of both logical inference and empirical fit. First, more research is required to assess whether or not the same mechanisms explaining the "absence of war" among liberal democracies are useful in explaining nuclear cooperation. After all, democracies do engage in conflict with other democracies, short of war. Second, the expectation that non-democracies would be less transparent and credible in their commitments and less reliable on ratification is often postulated, but very seldom explained or tested: it is more of a premise than a hypothesis. Third, the empirical evidence contradicts the notion that regimes, including nuclear ones, are less likely to emerge between mixed or non-democratic dyads. In fact, most international regimes in every issue-area emerged out of compromises among a wide variety of political systems.
The global nuclear nonproliferation regime is a case in point. At the regional level, democratic administrations in Pakistan and in India failed to agree to mutual denuclearization, while military dictatorships in Brazil and Argentina set in motion bilateral nuclear cooperation in 1980. A highly mixed and politically quite unstable group of Latin American states signed the Treaty of Tlatelolco in 1968, establishing a NWFZ. On the Korean peninsula, a relic of Cold War authoritarianism and a democratizing (but far from genuinely democratic) South began negotiations over a system of reciprocal inspections in 1991 (a process that is now, to be sure, derailed). In the Middle East, a mixed lot is negotiating regional arms control, including control of weapons of mass destruction, in the context of the multilateral peace process. Moreover, the diffusion of democracy might be expected to mitigate Israeli concerns with the credibility and reliability of its non-democratic neighbors; however, where radical Islamic forces are its bearers, democratization may not bode well for a security regime, given these forces' advocacy of total and final wars against infidels generally, and against Israel in particular.8/ Political freedom thus seems neither necessary nor sufficient for the emergence of a nuclear regime.
Perhaps the most severe problem lies in inferring the potential nuclear behavior of fence-sitters, without qualifications, from the experience of advanced industrialized democracies,9/ from whose history the democratic predisposition to avoid wars and build regimes with fellow democracies is overwhelmingly drawn. This raises the question of the extent to which democratic stability, far more abundant among industrialized states, plays a critical role in explaining the "zone of peace" these states have created. Second, there is the possibility that economic liberalization, rather than democracy, may be more useful in explaining nuclear cooperation,
ECONOMIC LIBERALIZATION, POLITICAL COALITIONS, AND NUCLEAR PREFERENCES
Indeed, it is my hypothesis that ruling coalitions pursuing economic liberalization are more likely to embrace regional nuclear regimes than their inward-looking, nationalist and radical-confessional counterparts. This hypothesis is based on two main assumptions. The first is that the kinds of ties binding actors (groups, sectors, parties, institutions) to economic and other international processes affect their conceptions of interests.10/ Such ties influence actors' definitions of what trade-offs are desirable or tolerable. For example, a state's decision to maintain ambiguity in nuclear intentions (e.g., by refusing full-scope safeguards or by cheating on NPT commitments) has involved, since the 1970s, a series of trade-offs: access to international markets, capital, investments, and technology has been curtailed, directly and indirectly.11/ Such trade-offs create domestic coalitions favoring or rejecting such linkages: groups that might otherwise pay little attention to their country's nuclear posture become more attentive to the elements of the international bargain. Interested actors both respond to, and anticipate, international constraints.
Second, nuclear postures are a response not merely to international constraints: the domestic consequences of alternative nuclear paths are no less important to political actors and coalitions. For instance, the political effects of doing away with nuclear ambiguity often includes the weakening of bloated state bureaucracies and industrial complexes that constitute an impediment to economic rationalization. Conversely, denuclearization tends to be part of a broader program of domestic reform that strengthens market-oriented forces and the political entrepreneurs and central economic institutions promoting their development. This has clearly been the case in Argentina and Brazil, where multibillion-dollar nuclear investments undertaken in the 1970s became primary casualties of the contraction of state activities in the 1980s and 1990s.
Thus, two basic types of coalition -- one advocating economic liberalization, the other opposing it -- may develop contrasting perspectives on both the domestic and international consequences of alternative nuclear paths.
Liberalizing coalitions. The interests of political coalitions favoring economic liberalization are generally internationalist; that is, they require openness to global market and institutional forces. A policy of economic liberalization implies a reduction of state control over markets and of barriers to trade, an expansion of private economic transactions and foreign investment, and the privatization of public-sector enterprises. Different liberalizing coalitions emphasize different aspects of economic liberalization, depending on their interest in specific issues, such as expanding exports, deregulating financial flows, opening the domestic market to foreign goods and investment, and reducing state entrepreneurial activities. Their selective and gradual agenda of economic liberalization explains why the adjective "liberalizing" is more appropriate than "liberal"; the state often plays a powerful role in steering this process. Political liberalization -- reduction of state monopoly over political life -- is not an immediate requirement for economic liberalization, at least during its initial phase.
For the most part, the pillars of liberalizing coalitions are liquid-asset holders and export-oriented firms -- including large banking and industrial complexes capable of surviving without state protection -- and state monetary agencies. They tend to be more receptive to structural adjustment policies,12/ and opposed to external confrontations with the international financial and investing community. The ability of big business (locally and foreign-owned) to influence domestic investment patterns and to move capital abroad gives them an important voice in shaping policy on domestic and external adjustment. Smaller firms engaged in exports or supplying internationalized enterprises can also be part of these coalitions, along with the highly-skilled labor force associated with these firms. Public and private managerial, technical, scientific, educational, information and service-oriented professional groups similarly tend to be oriented toward an open global economic and knowledge system.
The economic orientation of such coalitions, which strive to maximize their gains from international economic exchange, makes them more likely to be receptive to compromise nuclear postures that do not endanger their interests. These coalitions rely extensively on the global economy and on the political support of major powers within regimes and institutions involved in managing international economic relations. A policy of nuclear disarmament enhances their status with international institutions and powerful states, who associate these coalitions with the promise of democracy, rationalization and regional cooperation.
Related domestic considerations reinforce these coalitions' opposition to large-scale, ambiguous and unbounded nuclear programs: such programs often contribute to the ailments afflicting these countries' domestic political economy, such as the expansion of state power, the maintenance of unproductive and inflation-inducing military investments, and the perpetuation of rent-seeking patterns.13/ In other words, liberalizing coalitions do not merely trade away the right to have "the bomb" for the right to make money; they perceive little inherent benefit in a policy of nuclear ambiguity, for both domestic and international reasons. A restrained nuclear posture can secure certain international economic, financial and political benefits -- such as debt relief, export markets, technology transfer, food imports, aid and investments -- that can be used to maintain or broaden domestic political support and to strengthen the domestic institutional framework underpinning economic liberalization. In sum, cooperative regimes in the economic and security realms are mutually reinforcing; they spell transparency, predictability, a good reputation and the blessing of the international community. They also help carry out domestic policies largely in line with these coalitions' political and economic preferences.
Inward-looking, nationalist, and radical-confessional coalitions. The distributional consequences of economic liberalization also create coalitions that oppose liberalization. Such coalitions often reject orthodox stabilization plans imposed by the International Monetary Fund (IMF) and other financial institutions, and favor a more expansionist course. These inward-looking coalitions include popular sectors comprising unskilled blue-collar workers, white-collar and other state employees, and small businesses; firms that compete with imports and that have close ties to the state and domestic markets; underemployed intelligentsia, and politicians who fear the dismantling of state enterprises and the consequent erosion of their basis of political patronage. They may also include arms-importing military establishments, which are often adversely affected by adjustment programs.14/
In the Middle East and South Asia, nationalist coalitions often attract extremist religious movements. Such movements thrive on popular resentment over adjustment policies they regard as externally-imposed, reliance on foreign investment and the "Western" principles and norms embodied in most international regimes. The material basis for opposing internationalization and liberalization may be particularly strong where import-substitution and state-based industrial interests are powerful. In other cases, religious or ideological components may be the driving force. Very often these two tend to reinforce each other. Leaders of these logrolled coalitions of rent-seeking economic interests and militant religious, ethnic or cultural groups rely heavily on what Jack Snyder labels mythmaking; that is, they sell myths that justify the allocation of state resources to the wide array of interests backing an inward-looking strategy.15/ Their rejection of global markets and institutions is echoed in their adversarial regional postures. In the extreme form of nationalist coalitions, such as the one that supported Saddam Hussein, nuclear weapons often play a central (and more open) role in the call for final, "redeeming" solutions. Many such inward-looking, state-oriented (rather than market-oriented) economic leaderships, whether democratic or otherwise -- such as North Korea, India, Iraq, Libya and Cuba, and even Brazil and Argentina -- long resisted external pressures to join or comply with the global nonproliferation regime or any regional alternative to it.
The foregoing analysis of the relationship between political-economic strategies and nuclear postures suggests a pattern, not an infallible rule. Thus, domestic coalitions in an industrializing state may be strongly supportive of their country's integration within the international economy, while resisting other (political, security, environmental, human rights) global regimes; China is an example. However, international tolerance for attempts by ruling coalitions to disaggregate a state's allegiance to emerging global arrangements ("we will trade as freely as we repress and pollute") may be rapidly declining.
Coalitions of one type or the other come to power through electoral means where democratic institutions are in place and through more or less coercive methods elsewhere, often in alliance with the military. At times, a rough parity in the competition between these two basic kinds of coalition precludes the adoption of a clear-cut strategy concerning international economic, nuclear and other regimes, as in Argentina during much of the postwar era. At other times, one coalition is able to impose a relatively unchallenged path, as with South Korea, Taiwan and other East Asian countries. Most often, however, industrialization strategies incorporate different mixes of inward- and outward-looking instruments, and vary in the extent to which it is state officials or powerful societal forces that dominate the definition and implementation of strategy. This point underscores the need to understand differences between the ideal-types of coalitions outlined above and the more nuanced versions in the real world.16/ We therefore turn now to examine -- perforce, in a cursory manner -- the impact of coalition type on the nature of nuclear postures in four regions.
THE KOREAN PENINSULA
South Korea provides a classic example of a liberalizing coalition implementing a nuclear policy compatible with its fundamental interests and grand strategy of industrialization. Following a relatively brief import-substitution phase, state bureaucrats guided the country's integration in the global economy, leaning on foreign markets, loans, technology and investments. To embrace a nuclear deterrent, which the leadership considered doing in 1971, would have threatened that strategy and, consequently, the regime's viability. Thus, the coalition backing the Park regime responded to U.S. threats of a major break in bilateral economic relations by cancelling the incipient weapons program and ratifying the NPT in 1975. For a regime taking cues from a strong military establishment, this shift in nuclear posture makes the triumph of political-economic considerations in defining the country's survival strategy even more remarkable. By the 1980s, South Korea's export-oriented coalition included virtually all segments of business and labor. At the end of the decade, this coalition was actively pursuing a NWFZ, despite South Korea's unquestionable technical and industrial capacity to "beat" North Korea in a conventional or nuclear arms race. Despite a North Korean threat to turn Seoul into a "sea of fire," there seems to be little popular and governmental support for a South Korean nuclear deterrent, and few in the South believe the North would ever use an atomic weapon.
No doubt, hegemonic protection (that is, U.S. tactical nuclear weapons) was an important consideration in weighing denuclearization, but one should not exaggerate its impact. In the aftermath of Vietnam, the Nixon Doctrine, and the normalization of relations with Beijing, the South Korean leadership had reason to question the robustness of U.S. security guarantees. The prospects of U.S. economic sanctions were even more troubling than Pyongyang's threatening posture for a leadership that was acutely aware of U.S. contributions to the country's internal political stability and, in essence, to the regime's survival. The potential for disrupting an average annual rate of growth of over 10 percent and for domestic political turmoil was a powerful threat to reckon with.
The North Korean case approaches the opposite, inward-looking, nationalist coalition ideal-type as closely as any real case can. Self-reliance (juche) and the cult of the leadership became central political instruments of mythmaking, somewhat like a secular version of radical confessionalism. Nuclear weapons (or ambiguity about their possession) became the ultimate expression of national independence and technical achievement that the regime could wield as evidence of its own viability; this was particularly critical once the South's economic vigor became apparent. An independent and ambiguous stand on nuclear matters was thus an important ingredient in the North's political-economic grand strategy of self-reliance, and one with high payoffs for soothing a restive military and nuclear establishment and its nationalist allies in the bureaucracy. The United States and North Korea's former Soviet protector coerced it into ratifying the NPT in 1985, an event that, tellingly, followed a feeble North Korean attempt at economic liberalization. However, giving new meaning to the difference between formal and effective commitments to non-proliferation principles, North Korea continued to reject full-scope IAEA (International Atomic Energy Agency) inspections de facto, even after the United States had removed tactical nuclear weapons from South Korea in 1991.
This outcome highlights the difficulty of reducing North Korea's behavior, as paranoiac as it may seem, exclusively to security concerns. What compelled the North Korean leadership to drag its feet on the nuclear issue was the fact that U.S., South Korean, Japanese and multilateral promises of improved economic ties did not materialize.17/ With this, the regime's expectation of preventing its own collapse, by relying on economic reforms, evaporated. In the absence of tangible international commitments to provide economic aid to North Korea, the incipient liberalizing forces in North Korea lost out to the hard-liners in the military and nuclear establishment. By March 1993, North Korea announced its intention to withdraw from the NPT, unleashing an international crisis. Despite the efforts of very powerful strategic allies and very powerful strategic adversaries, North Korea was not persuaded to relinquish nuclear aspirations for an extended period of time. Domestic receptivity is an important intervening factor in the relationship between hegemonic pressures and the responses of fence-sitters.
SOUTH ASIA
The coalition shaping economic and industrial policy in India's post-independence era embraced a classical import-substitution model of industrialization, aimed at avoiding vulnerability to international markets and economic institutions. It strongly criticized international regimes as constructs of Western powers, opposed the non-proliferation regime as the crowning example of neocolonialism, and conspicuously exploded a nuclear device in 1974. Advocates of an Indian nuclear deterrent pointed to China's nuclear status as a convenient justification for their position, despite China's clear "no first use" policy. A group of Congress party officials favored nuclear weapons for domestic political reasons (polls indicated majority support for such weapons), to counteract the party's discredit for India's defeat by China in 1962.18/ A similar overall inward-looking strategy at first characterized Pakistan under democratically-elected Zulfiqar Ali Bhutto, a populist who pursued nuclear weapons and discussed the merits of an "Islamic bomb." President-General Zia ul-Haq maintained a patronage system and used Islam as a source of national identity, but sought greater reliance on the West; political survival required straddling antagonistic nuclear postures, or the maintenance of ambiguity.
India took initial steps at economic liberalization under the Janata government (1977-80), one far less friendly than any of its predecessors to state-centered inward-looking policies in general and to the nuclear-industrial complex in particular. Prime Minister Morarji Desai vehemently opposed India's nuclear weapons program. Subsequent incipient Indian and Pakistani efforts at liberalizing their domestic markets and foreign trade during the 1980s coincided with a modest attempt by Indian Prime Minister Rajiv Gandhi and Pakistani Prime Minister Benazir Bhutto to initiate nuclear cooperation.19/ But in India, liberalization (including lowering of some import barriers) encountered heavy opposition from beneficiaries of the old model, bent on keeping international economic institutions and foreign investment at arms' length. Business groups, state central financial agencies and the professional middle class supported the relaxation of state controls, but many opposed lowering trade barriers. The rank and file in the Congress party, public-sector employees, the intelligentsia, which is mostly state-employed, and some rural sectors (known as "middle peasants") rejected all efforts at liberalization, internal and external. Nationalist, inward-looking constituencies, including the technical and entrepreneurial military-industrial complex, were increasingly under attack, but not yet retreating.
India's government under P.V. Narasimha Rao represents a stronger attempt at economic liberalization; it has shaken subsidized sectors and state-owned industries, actively pursued European Community, Japanese and U.S. investments and World Bank and IMF loans, and allowed Finance Minister Manmohan Singh to rechart not only India's economic course, but its foreign policy as well. Very early in its tenure, and following a strong electoral showing by the opposition Bharatiya Janata Party (BJP), Rao's minority government did not choose to embrace a 1991 Pakistani overture for a NWFZ, but neither did it reject the offer completely, and it agreed to exchange information with Pakistan on the location of the two countries' respective nuclear facilities.20/ The Pakistani proposals notably followed the November 1990 ascendancy of Prime Minister Nawaz Sharif, whose trademark was an emphasis on free markets, economic liberalization, foreign investment and international financial aid; urban business, commercial and professional groups backed this strategy. A representative of industrial interests, Sharif publicly rejected the label "fundamentalist" and lamented the political energy invested in debates over Islamization "while the world is marching fast to meet the challenges (of) the twenty-first century."21/ Yet Sharif, like his predecessor Benazir Bhutto, proved to be too willing to undertake public projects with high political payoffs, which helped to bankrupt Pakistan.
With the ousting of Prime Minister Sharif, former World Bank vice president Moeen Qureshi challenged the power of entrenched elites during his brief transitional administration, giving the Central Bank new powers to control government deficits while he attempted to freeze nuclear activities. The policies of Sharif and Qureshi of attracting foreign loans and investments required a dramatic reduction of defense spending, which antagonized segments of the Pakistani military.22/ The second administration of Benazir Bhutto, re-elected in October 1993, rejected Qureshi's reforms and remained responsive to feudal landowners, the bureaucracy and the army; it also pledged to protect Pakistan's nuclear program.23/
The platform of India's main opposition party, the radical-confessional Hindu BJP, combines calls to ban foreign loans, investments and imports with a call to build and deploy nuclear weapons.24/ Cashing in on widespread popular resentment against the West, both for its economic success and for imposing a nuclear cartel, the BJP also enjoys increasing support from import-competing industries such as food processing, automobile manufacturing, banking and communications. The party thus expressly rejects a wide range of "Western" regimes, from the NPT, to GATT, the World Bank, and IMF-imposed restructuring plans, to the policies of international development agencies that favor population control and the eradication of illiteracy.
Many of the BJP positions have been echoed by Pakistan's militant Islamic party Jamaat-i-Islami, which challenged what it regards as the Westernized policies of the Sharif coalition.25/ President Ghulam Isaq Khan, representing the nationalist political camp, was thought to support efforts to produce a nuclear weapon, and to have refused to allow elected politicians to negotiate over nuclear matters.26/
How strong such radical nationalist-confessional coalitions become is bound to be a key factor in shaping the Kashmir crisis and South Asia's nuclear future.
THE MIDDLE EAST
Among the current ruling coalitions in the Middle East are oil-exporting industries in the Gulf and the Arabian peninsula; tourist-based, commercial-agriculture, and munfatihun ("openers") economies in Egypt and Jordan; high-tech-export-oriented industrialists in Israel; and influential Sunni merchants in Damascus. These coalitions advocate openness to international markets, investments and tourism; cooperative relations with international financial institutions; and support for the Arab-Israeli peace process. Most have ratified the NPT and have consistently advanced NWFZ proposals at UN fora.27/ Leading exemplars of such coalitions -- Iran under the Shah and Egypt under President Sadat -- played entrepreneurial roles in organizing support for a NWFZ. This behavior does not merely imply a passive acceptance of security concessions in exchange for economic advantages, as opponents of liberalizing coalitions often argue. The domestic consequences of cooperative regional postures have positive attractions for advocates of reform. They help the coalition politically in coping with the socioeconomic havoc left by declining oil prices, bloated bureaucracies and economic mismanagement, overpopulation, militarization and foreign policy adventurism. Infitah (economic liberalization) was at the heart of a grand strategy for a new, triumphant Egypt, introduced at a time of scarce resources and dwindling state revenues. It required foreign capital, financial assistance and Western technology, as well as a commitment to private capitalist accumulation, all of which secured the backing of a powerful coalition of business interests and technocrats. Infitah played an important role in persuading President Sadat to negotiate an unprecedented peace treaty with Israel. The Camp David agreements, in turn, marginalized the domestic opposition to Sadat's regional politics, even if it radicalized the Islamic fringes. It is quite suggestive that infitah was launched in 1974, the same year Egypt first proposed, with Iran, a NWFZ.28/
Different strains of radical Islamic challengers offer themselves as an alternative to liberalizing coalitions. Islamic blocs include "bourgeois fractions, some rural agrarian capitalists, notables and estate-owners, and the virtually proletarianized members of the state-employed petit-bourgeoisie, the underemployed intelligentsia, and the large student population."29/ These blocs propose a new political economy that, for the most part, appears incompatible with a regional nuclear regime. Opposition to liberalizing coalitions often involves a rejection of ties to the international economy and its perceived associated scourges: inequality, corruption, unemployment and enslaving indebtedness. In addition, militant Islamic political movements promote a new social order that is not receptive to the idea of a comprehensive peace settlement, let alone a regional nuclear regime.30/ The domestic political appeal of these movements increases primarily with their ability to satisfy popular socioeconomic and educational needs, and in some cases, with calls for extreme "redeeming" solutions.31/ However, the ability of such radical coalitions to "deliver" on the warfare (jihad) side, by investing in military infrastructure, is limited by their need to secure welfare and redistribution. These tasks are much harder to fulfill without preserving the export-oriented rentier state and, therefore, preserving extensive ties to the world economy.32/
Radical Islamic movements are not an ideological monolith; their political-economy themes vary, as do their approaches to the West. Moderate Islamic movements also exist, even if their influence in Middle East politics has so far been somewhat limited.33/ Some of these movements are less concerned with military buildups and exotic weapons than with the socioeconomic transformation of their societies. Such differences are neglected if one focuses only on the behavior of the two Islamic republics in existence, Iran and Sudan, and on the political platforms of militant movements. These do not bode well for compromise solutions to regional security predicaments. Likewise, the most forceful message of the radical Islamic bloc in the 1993 Jordanian elections was opposition to an Arab-Israeli peace settlement, relegating the rejection of IMF-induced economic reform to a secondary theme.
Iran. The Shah is credited with embarking on a large-scale nuclear energy program, and an interest in nuclear weapons has even been imputed to him; yet his regime pioneered a Middle East NWFZ. Following the Islamic revolution in 1979, Iran discontinued its active role in promoting a NWFZ. The emerging Islamic Republic of Iran acquired many of the characteristics of the radical-confessional inward-looking ideal-type, expressing contempt for principles of diplomatic extraterritoriality, individual freedoms and anti-terrorism, and executing a national redistribution of wealth from the private to the public sector. Although an NPT signatory, Iran is suspected of pursuing a weapons program, an accusation President Hashemi Rafsanjani has denied. However, Vice-president Sayed Ayatollah Mohajerani argued in 1992 that "we, the Muslims, must cooperate to produce an atomic bomb, regardless of UN efforts to prevent proliferation."34/
Although mention of Iran's "moderate" wing often raises incredulity, outward-looking undercurrents do appear to be alive, if not well. Teheran's Bazari (bazaar) merchants and moneylenders have backed President Rafsanjani's attempts at reform and at reducing state control over the economy. Their gradually increasing control of the 270-seat Parliament could consolidate their struggle for domestic political dominance.35/ They call for privatization of an extensive network of state-run factories and power plants, and are stepping up pressures for increased trade with Europe and Asia and for a utilitarian -- as opposed to an ideological -- approach to foreign policy. The unresolved contest between liberalizing and radical Islamic blocs may help explain the unclear and unstable nature of Iran's nuclear postures in the past decade.
Iraq. Iraq's Ba'athist regime approximates the inward-looking, state-based, nationalizing, militarized ideal-type rather well. Saddam Hussein's more recent use of Islam is an ideological ornamentation with occasional political payoffs; it does not alter -- in fact, reinforces -- the basic rejection of economic liberalism that Ba'athism embraced in the first place. His regime's survival can be traced to a combination of repressive controls (involving abominable human-rights abuses) and successful redistributive policies.36/ The entrenched combined power of state-enterprise bureaucracies, import-substituting interests, and their respective beneficiaries among the professional, construction and working class may have been responsible for preventing change beyond a limited, tentative effort at economic liberalization.
The external expression of this domestic model was a formal rejection of the international economic order and of the Camp David peace agreements, a reliance on the Soviet Union, advocacy of nonalignment, and a "hawkish" position within the Organization of Petroleum Exporting Countries (OPEC). Iraq's nuclear program represented a crowning symbol of the interests and wherewithal of this ruling coalition emphasizing self-reliance. The activities of the UN Special Commission on Iraqi disarmament have neutralized a substantial portion of that program, in an unusual case of forced denuclearization. Genuine Iraqi openness to any regional cooperation -- nuclear or otherwise -- may have to await a new leadership that reflects the interests of a coalition oriented to global trade and investments and to the emerging international institutional order.
Israel. Israel's developmental strategy in the immediate post-independence era combined statism and import-substitution with some dependence on foreign capital and agricultural exports. Despite a general political and economic orientation toward the West, Israel developed high mistrust of international institutions, where Third World majorities could automatically endorse Arab positions regardless of substantive merit. It is assumed that a small group around Prime Minister Ben-Gurion, who embodied statism (Mamlachtiut), developed the foundations of a nuclear weapons program in the 1950s and 1960s, never acknowledging its existence. The ambiguous nature of this program relieved a succession of precarious, unwieldy ruling coalitions from the need to debate a program about which little agreement could be found.37/
External and especially alliance considerations and their impact on domestic constituencies played an important role in the way in which different coalition members defined their positions on nuclear weapons. For instance, in the 1950s, the leadership of the Mapam and Ahdut Avoda parties (both politically powerful within Israel's General Federation of Labor, Histadrut) forcefully rejected nuclear deterrence; the policy would have threatened not only relations with the Soviet Union, but also the anti-nuclear feelings of the pro-Soviet constituencies on which these two parties relied. Leading members of the largest bloc in the Labor coalition (Mapai) similarly opposed reliance on nuclear deterrence. In the late 1960s, Prime Minister (and previously Finance Minister) Levy Eshkol and Finance Minister Pinhas Sapir conceived an incipient policy of economic liberalization aimed at promoting export-led and high-tech industrialization. By that time, not only did dependence on foreign capital leap, but donors (including the United States) applied much more restrictive conditions than those characterizing earlier discretionary capital inflows. As Michael Barnett argues, the Israeli state at that time became "more beholden to foreign actors to stabilize its financial life."38/ Mapai's leaders were not about to endanger the nascent domestic strategy or its external underpinnings (international markets and a political alliance with the West) by being unresponsive to United States concerns over Israel's nuclear designs. Eshkol is credited with attempts to rein in Israel's nuclear program. The political windfalls of such steps for Eshkol's Mapai faction included weakening a program that since Ben-Gurion, had enjoyed access to unsupervised budgetary sources.
In the last decade, two basic modalities have come to characterize Israeli coalition politics. On the one hand, Labor-led coalitions tend to attract support from the urban professional and middle class, from high-tech industrialists, highly-skilled labor, and export-oriented cooperative agriculture. It was Labor's Shimon Peres who designed and implemented the economic reform and currency stabilization plan of the mid-1980s, albeit in the context of a government of national unity with Likud. Labor coalitions (which include smaller, secular, left-of-center parties) are more receptive to international institutions, territorial compromise, regional regimes and arms control agreements. With the exception of Ben-Gurion and his group (which eventually formed a new party, Rafi) during the 1950s, most of the Labor party has traditionally opposed reliance on nuclear deterrence. Many influential Labor leaders have favored a NWFZ.39/ Prime Minister Yitzhak Rabin declared in 1974, in response to Defense Minister Moshe Dayan's call for nuclear weapons: "Attempts to rely on mystical weapons are negative trends."40/ In 1975 at the United Nations General Assembly, Israel's Foreign Minister Yigal Allon (of the Ahdut Avoda party) proposed direct negotiations over a regional NWFZ, and by 1980, Israel was voting in favor of the Egyptian NWFZ proposal, submitted regularly to the UN since 1974. Yet, in the context (until very recently) of a rigid Arab refusal to recognize the existence of the state of Israel, let alone acknowledge its security concerns, any attempt by Labor to endorse a unilateral denuclearization would have entailed prohibitive political costs.
On the other hand, populist Likud-led coalitions, a bloc that in Israel's early years represented free-enterprise liberalism, are now more susceptible to demands from nationalist economic interests (including small business, blue-collar and underemployed workers, development towns, and West Bank and Gaza settlers) and from the orthodox, including some radical religious and nationalist constituencies. They tend to be more dismissive of international institutions and distrustful of their objectives, and to use the myth of self-reliance to gather political support from an array of economic and ideological groups, most of which reject a territorial compromise with Palestinians.41/ Menachem Begin's Likud government bombed Iraq's Osirak reactor in 1981 (in a pre-elections period), against the opposition of important Labor leaders who, sensitive to the response of allies and institutions like the International Atomic Energy Agency, sought more time for diplomacy.42/ Prominent Likud leaders are associated with opposition to a NWFZ, although the party has no declared policy on this issue.
Labor's political comeback in 1992 foreshadows greater Israeli willingness to embrace a regime, and eventually a NWFZ. First, the Labor coalition has led, rather than followed, public opinion in matters of national security; it presented the public with a fait accompli in the form of the September 1993 Declaration of Principles recognizing the Palestine Liberation Organization. A 3:2 margin of voter approval followed. Moreover, the Labor coalition is more sensitive to Israel's international standing, and to the domestic political and economic consequences of such status.43/ A recent statement by Deputy Foreign Minister Yossi Beilin summarizes the aims of Labor diplomacy: "to use the new situation in order to become a more welcome member of the international club."44/ The coalition emphasizes the exigencies of economic survival, privatization and international competitiveness as well as the futility of technological fixes as the solution to Israel's security dilemma. This approach threatens the rents and political influence of military-industrial groups and state bureaucracies, while expanding the opportunities for civilian-oriented private entrepreneurship and the power and autonomy of economic agencies such as the Central Bank.
The future of Israel's alleged nuclear arsenal is on the agenda of the Arms Control Group in the multilateral peace negotiations, although there is disagreement whether non-conventional weapons should be discussed at the outset or at the end of the process. It is doubtful that representatives from the Labor government can politically afford to agree to any arrangements on the nuclear issue prior to the achievement of a comprehensive peace settlement and resolution of outstanding problems with Iran and Iraq. There is a strong proclivity among Labor leaders and their core supporters to do away with most barriers to effective regional cooperation. However, the need to secure swing votes (potentially attracted to Labor and its political allies in all but their security postures) may require caution on the question of trade-offs for peace, and in the rate at which they are delivered. On the other hand, the government of Egypt and other incumbent coalitions in the region may be unlikely to obtain popular ratification of a comprehensive peace settlement that omits the curtailment of Israel's nuclear capabilities, at least at some point in the future. The successful completion and implementation of such a settlement will deflate the mythmaking potential of radical-confessional groups on both sides. Despite promising developments, the concluding chapter of the Middle East's NWFZ has yet to be written.
THE SOUTHERN CONE OF LATIN AMERICA: ARGENTINA AND BRAZIL
The presidency of Juan D. Peron in Argentina epitomized the national populist economic model that vied for control of the state for half a century. It involved a coalition of national small and medium-sized firms involved in import-substitution industrialization, state firms producing the required infrastructural inputs, and popular sectors represented in the central trade union organization (the General Labor Confederation). The external expression of national populism was a challenge to free trade and the unpredictability of the international market, and also a rejection of foreign borrowing and investment as well as of membership in the IMF and the World Bank.
Peron actively pursued nuclear capabilities in the early 1950s, and announced the country's mastery of fusion technology in 1953, on the basis of a false claim by expatriate Austrian physicist Ronald Richter, who managed Argentina's nuclear program at the time.45/ The origins of a well-funded nuclear program in Argentina are thus deeply rooted in the national populism of the Peron era; such origins endowed the program with the myth of self-reliance.
After the military coup of 1955 deposed Peron, a tripartite division of state industrial assets among Argentina's armed services allowed the navy to shelter the nuclear program during an unstable succession of mostly military regimes. This period was notable for alternating stop-go economic and industrial policy cycles, reflecting the inability of either coalition -- the one supporting liberalization, the other opposing it -- to prevail politically for a sustained period of time. Attempts at liberalization, as with President Arturo Frondizi's acceptance of an IMF stabilization plan and of foreign exploitation of Argentina's oil reserves, coincided with attempts in the 1960s to curtail the nuclear program and reduce its autonomy. The military administration of Lt. General Jorge Rafael Videla in 1976, strongly influenced by Economic Minister Jose Alfredo Martinez de Hoz and his orthodox policies, challenged the costly nationalist-mercantilist orientation of the nuclear program, the bloated and inefficient state sector and the non-competitive national private industry. Although privatization and dwindling governmental expenditures threatened the nuclear program, the navy was able to defend it throughout the 1970s and 1980s. Martinez de Hoz was ousted, and no coalition supporting widespread liberal economic reforms was strong enough to implement such a program until the early 1990s.
In Brazil, the administration of Getulio Vargas in the early 1950s evoked many of the same elements of national populism as in Argentina under Peron. Restrictions on foreign investment led to a refusal by the World Bank to finance the Vargas strategy of industrialization, or that of his successors, until 1964. In the nuclear realm, this policy was expressed in the regime's attempt to develop independent national nuclear capabilities as early as the 1950s.46/ In 1952, President Vargas approved directives to the National Security Council demanding "specific compensations" in the form of transfer of technical know-how on plant construction, and delivery of equipment and materials for chemical treatment, in exchange for any sale of uranium or thorium to the United States. Admiral Alvaro Alberto, the director of the National Research Council (CNPq), attempted to purchase three ultra-centrifuge systems for uranium enrichment from Bonn in 1954. That year interim President Cafe Filho, who succeeded Vargas and launched a policy to attract foreign investments, dismissed Alberto and allowed the United States to take over the monopoly on uranium research and extraction for a period of two years.
The old pro-Vargas coalition supported the ascendancy of President Juscelino Kubitschek in 1955, while anti-statist groups and supporters of free trade opposed it. The Kubitschek coalition resisted IMF stabilization programs that threatened its power basis. In 1956, President Kubitschek appointed a parliamentary commission of inquiry into nuclear policy following a denunciation of alleged improper U.S. influences exerted upon the administration of President Cafe Filho. The commission's report urged the pursuit of independent nuclear capabilities and the creation of a National Atomic Energy Commission (CNEN), directly answerable to the president of the republic. With the ascension of a new national-populist team in 1961, President Janio Quadros reaffirmed a nationalist nuclear policy, based on natural uranium (which granted Brazil fuel independence), a policy in tune with the broader developmental priorities that characterized his short presidency. Quadros's successor Jožo Goulart (1961-63) maintained the emphasis on national nuclear capabilities and approved a Nuclear Energy Law subordinating the Nuclear Energy Commission directly to the presidency, as a way to increase its bureaucratic independence.
Unlike the nationalist inward-looking coalitions backing Argentina's President Peron and Brazil's Presidents Quadros and Goulart, the military regimes that have intervened in Brazil and Argentina since the 1960s have shifted -- without abandoning import-substitution altogether -- to greater reliance on foreign direct investment, industrial exports and indebted industrialization. This strategy required stronger economic ties with the United States, Western Europe, Japan, and international financial institutions. Although formally headed by repressive military rulers with some constituencies that favored nuclear weapons, these coalitions of technocrats, industrialists and bankers maintained considerable control over economic policy. They were thus able to resist pressures for a nuclear posture that could trigger international penalties or other restrictions on technology transfer. Throughout these years, nuclear policy revealed two main features. On the one hand, both Brazil and Argentina continued their longstanding rejection of the NPT as a discriminatory tool of nuclear powers, and their resistance to making the regional Tlatelolco NWFZ effective on their territory. On the other hand, they refrained from developing nuclear weapons and from threatening to do so.47/ The beginnings of moderate nuclear cooperation can be traced to the late 1970s and, more specifically, to the 1980 agreements signed in Foz do Iguacu by Presidents-General Videla of Argentina and Jožo Baptista Figueiredo of Brazil.
In the mid-1980s, Brazil's President Jose Sarney implemented a nationalist-populist mixture of domestic heterodoxy and anti-IMF policy that led eventually to Brazil's 1987 debt moratorium. In an attempt to maintain both business and popular support, President Raul Alfonsin defined a heterodox adjustment policy in Argentina, relying on neither the old radical Peronist populism nor the radical orthodox rhetoric of the military's policy under Videla, while preserving a cooperative stance with international creditors. The new democratic administrations, neither of which was prepared to adopt orthodox liberal medicine for their countries' economic ailments, proceeded with a moderate pace, but no real breakthrough, in both economic liberalization and nuclear cooperation. In Brazil, sections of the military continued to develop a "parallel program" with weapons applications, even after attempts, through the Constitution drafted in 1988, to place all nuclear activities under democratic control.48/
By the late 1980s, drops in real wages, price freezes, and tax reforms alienated Sarney's popular constituencies, forcing Brazil to turn to an IMF-style orthodox stabilization package. The Argentine government was at this time particularly careful to provide strong reassurance to its banking and industrial firms, in light of populist challenges to the state during the late 1980s. At the end of the decade, both President Fernando Collor de Mello of Brazil and President Carlos S. Menem of Argentina supported shock economic programs unambiguously committed to effective economic liberalization and structural adjustment.
The liberalizing Menem revolution reduced a Weimar-style inflation level to single digits, balanced the budget, privatized many public services, and attracted an avalanche of foreign investment. The external dimension of these policies included an unprecedented embrace not only of liberal trade rules but also of other international regimes, including missile control.49/ Following his election, President Collor was equally committed to liberalizing Brazil's economy, a policy that won him an approval rating of close to 90 percent in early 1990.
By November of 1990, Brazil and Argentina agreed explicitly, for the first time, to renounce nuclear weapons and to establish mutual verification and inspection procedures, which were ultimately approved in December 1991.50/ The two countries also expressed their intention to put into effect an updated version of the regional Tlatelolco Treaty, and Brazil's President Collor closed down presumed nuclear weapons test sites. After more than 35 years of unassailed navy control, Argentina's nuclear program was now at the mercy of President Menem's director of planning, whose major goal was the privatization of nuclear activities. Aided by advisors from large Argentine corporations and joint ventures, the Menem administration neutralized the program's sensitive nuclear facilities. Menem has gone as far as expressing unilateral readiness to ratify the NPT by the time of the 1995 Extension and Review Conference.51/ In Brazil, following Collor's resignation in 1992 over a corruption scandal, his successor Itamar Franco began wooing a nationalist and military constituency, attacking international financial institutions and their domestic "allies," and endorsing statements on Brazil's sovereignty in nuclear matters. However, nationalist forces failed to prevent Brazil's House of Deputies, under heavy pressure from the Foreign and Economic ministries, from approving the mutual inspection agreements with Argentina in late 1993.52/ The Senate is expected to follow suit. Brazil's opposition to NPT ratification may well be explained as a side-payment to the nationalist camp, including portions of the military.
LESSONS AND IMPLICATIONS
This cross-regional analysis suggests that the political-economic nature of domestic coalitions and the choice of nuclear postures are related. I suggest that this relationship can be traced to the type of industrialization strategy these coalitions embrace. Liberalizing coalitions strive to maximize their gains from international economic exchange. Their receptivity to compromise regional nuclear postures secures them access to international economic regimes and the political support of major powers. Denuclearization is also quite compatible with the domestic agenda of liberalizing the economy and reining in adversarial political forces and institutions. In contrast, nationalist and radical-confessional coalitions logroll economic interests and militant groups that regard nuclear weapons as a useful political tool, to rally opposition to global markets and regimes and the settlement of regional conflicts.
As with most propositions about the sources of state behavior, this argument suggests no more than a probabilistic relationship. However, these assumptions do seem to help explain the behavior of states (a) operating in different regional security contexts; (b) with different associations with hegemonic powers; and (c) over time, throughout a historical succession of alternating coalition-types. The Middle East, the Korean peninsula and South Asia offered a natural quasi-experimental ground to examine the impact of different political regimes, controlling for the intensity of the security dilemma and the presence of hegemons providing protection. Under comparable regional structural contexts, we would have expected to find similar responses, but we do not. And under disparate security-related conditions -- compare the Southern Cone with the Middle East, the Korean peninsula or South Asia -- some states embraced similar policies of nuclear ambiguity for lengthy periods of time. A wide variety of domestic political regime types (democratic and otherwise) converged in cooperative practices, despite expectations from the theories connecting democracy and cooperation.
The cross-regional and longitudinal analysis suggests that where liberalizing coalitions had the upper hand, nuclear policy shifted toward more cooperative nuclear postures. Nationalist-confessional coalitions, in contrast, shied away from any commitments for effective denuclearization. Moreover, where the domestic interests potentially affected by external sanctions were most concentrated and coherent, and less challenged domestically, as in South Korea and Taiwan, the shift in nuclear policy was relatively swift. The stronger the coalition supporting economic liberalization grew, the more clear-cut the departure from nuclear ambiguity was (even where the security context deteriorated, as in the Korean peninsula). This is illustrated by Argentina's commitment to the full-scope safeguards regime in the early 1990s, following the consolidation of political forces supporting economic liberalization. It is also clear from the example of South Africa's acceptance of NPT arrangements in 1991, even as it disclosed past attempts to produce a bomb. In another example, Spain endorsed the NPT when a liberalizing coalition eager to join the European Community was able to put the inward-looking, nationalist policies of the Franco era behind it.
In contrast, the weaker the liberalizing coalitions -- as was the case historically in India and Israel, Argentina until the early 1990s, and Iran today -- the more politically constrained they were in curbing nuclear programs. Weak liberalizing coalitions are often less able to defend themselves from the accusation of selling out; their very weakness also renders them more dependent on additional domestic partners. Liberalizing coalitions walk a tightrope to sustain their legitimacy: they must not only deliver on their promises but also preserve fluid external ties while avoiding the appearance of foreign subordination.53/ Such conditions may help explain the hesitation of the Rao government in India to promise effective denuclearization, or Brazil's initial wariness under Itamar Franco to implement it.
Of all states (beyond the original five nuclear powers) that have considered a nuclear option in the last three decades, not one endorsed a NWFZ while under a nationalist coalition. Only liberalizing coalitions undertook effective commitments to denuclearization. The North Korean case may offer fresh insight into the process by which economic liberalization, coalition survival and nuclear postures become entangled. There are indications that the same political forces staunchly opposed to economic liberalization are using the nuclear issue to stave off the end of the present regime.
What are the more general implications for theories of international cooperation and regimes? First, the approach suggested here points to a more precise link between economic liberalism and the probability of cooperation than general theories of interdependence have postulated. Rather than assuming that the expanded domestic welfare resulting from free trade fosters cooperative preferences, it suggests that where free-trade coalitions prevail, their interests at home and abroad dictate compatible security regimes. The gains from trade need not be highly concentrated nor contribute to widespread societal welfare, at least in the short term, to have this effect. Moreover, cooperation does not depend on the extent of economic interdependence between or among the regional participants in a regime. Finally, my argument is more specific about whose absolute gains matter in the analysis of cooperation: the gains that matter are those of particular coalitions.
Second, this last point places more constraints on purely neorealist formulations beyond those discussed above. The preferences, domestic and international, of domestic ruling coalitions matter a great deal. These coalitions evaluate costs and benefits with an eye to strengthening their political standing at home, and they define the balance between the costs (if any) of nuclear cooperation and the overall gains from participating in global regimes. To say that once these coalitions embrace an internationalist strategy of industrialization they become more sensitive to pressures from powerful states and international institutions is not the same as arguing that foreign pressures or inducements singlehandedly, and invariably, account for the outcome. Such pressures were a constant for most of the Cold War era, yet they cannot settle the puzzle of why they triggered regime-oriented behavior at certain times and not others, and among certain states and not others. The accession of contending domestic coalitions provides a more powerful predictor of such dynamics and variability. Identifying the domestic conditions underlying behavioral shifts takes us several steps beyond structural explanations in understanding how external and internal factors interact to produce changes in nuclear postures. THE IMPACT OF INTERNATIONAL INSTITUTIONS
How do international institutions affect the domestic balance of power between coalitions, and thus, as a second-order effect, their respective nuclear postures? As allies of liberalizing coalitions, the international institutions that provide credit (World Bank, IMF, private banks) and that define the terms of trade and investment (GATT, regional common markets) can play an important role in the political longevity of these coalitions. Imposing harsh and widespread structural adjustments can undermine these coalitions' legitimacy and survival, and weaken their capacity to gather support for regional security regimes. The failures of some liberalizing coalitions in the Arab world (and of the international institutions within which their interests are embedded) to bring about a genuine socioeconomic transformation in the region has provided fertile soil for the rise of radical Islamic challengers. To prevent further erosion of popular support for liberalizing coalitions, international economic regimes must encourage domestic redistribution.54/ Tight conditionality arrangements have been ineffective anyway, whereas securing a stable political environment improves the borrowers' ability to attract investments, repay debts and stem authoritarian challenges. The IMF and the World Bank could return to their true calling by lending for economic development, stabilization and recovery, rather than helping debtors pay their debts to big banks.
In other words, the survival of liberalizing coalitions requires that the benefits from a cooperative nuclear posture -- in trade, investments, removal from export control lists, debt-relief and aid -- be distributed more broadly, beyond just the concentrated interests which sustain these coalitions. Providing resources, compensatory payments and relief from the pressures of international competition can weaken domestic opposition to liberalization and pragmatism. Such efforts may build on a wave of growing popular awareness of the opportunity costs of arms races. Furthermore, a shift in the style of foreign institutional intervention toward effective consultation over domestic political needs, and more active participation of developing countries in the decision-making process within international institutions, can deflate nationalist resentment. Such an approach may help these institutions tame extreme views and foster a form of liberalism, even one attentive to moderate confessional aspirations, that would view regional and international regimes positively. The other side of this coin, of course, is the power of liberalizing coalitions to "use" the threat from nationalists and radical-confessional movements to extract concessions from their international partners and to alleviate the conditions for continued credit and investment. This "reverse conditionality" will continue to be part of the bargaining strategies of struggling liberalizing coalitions in the future.
International institutions can strengthen the hands of certain domestic institutions at the expense of others. For example, externally-induced structural adjustment efforts often threaten military-industrial complexes while strengthening those in charge of reform (particularly finance ministries, central banks and export-promotion bureaus). Similarly, international pressures for human-rights standards empower the domestic groups responsible for monitoring compliance, at the expense of repressive agencies. Environmental regimes endow local institutional networks with the ability, backed by unprecedented legal powers, to challenge certain industrial activities such as nuclear energy production. The resulting coalitional balances are more likely to reinforce openness and receptivity to nuclear regimes than the coalitions and institutions they are replacing. Interests opposed to nuclear weapons could become more concentrated (and therefore, more attractive partners for logrolling) than those that favor them.
Finally, the fact that international regimes strengthen the influence of the most powerful countries that created them is not lost on developing countries, particularly fence-sitters, or on those in transition to market-oriented economies. If such regimes continue to be regarded as instruments for exercising control over the less powerful, their legitimacy could be eroded. But this can be ameliorated if the regimes' injunctions are universally binding, especially where they require the elimination of nuclear arsenals, as in Article VI of the Nonproliferation Treaty. CONCLUSIONS
In this article, I offer a framework for understanding the domestic sources of nonproliferation-regime creation by outlining how contending coalitions affect nuclear postures. The growing attention to domestic factors has mostly been directed at understanding the structure of interests within a specific issue area to explain cooperation (or its absence) in that same area, but understanding outcomes in the security arena requires a broader consideration of how political-economic strategies affect security choices. Such an approach helps specify what early neoliberal-institutionalism left unexplained: where the preference to cooperate comes from. By relying on a single analytical category, this approach transcends the practice of nonproliferation studies of explaining each country or region through a list of individualized peculiarities.
The evidence points to an association between strategies of industrialization and nuclear postures that is worthy of both theoretical and policymaking consideration. The findings suggest that the credibility of commitments by fence-sitters may be more affected by what kind of domestic political-economic coalition underwrites them than by the institutional constraints of democracy. Where these coalitions rely for their domestic political survival on an open economic system, they will not only be more susceptible to international inducements to cooperate but will favor denuclearization for its domestic effects as well. State structures influence the fate of different coalitions and, in turn, are changed by them; states are both the agents of liberalization and the victims of it. The performance of coalitions varies with the nature and strength of technocratic agencies on the one hand, and of rent-seeking actors and their challengers on the other. Exploring how this variation accounts for different paths to regional denuclearization may be a logical next step. Additional research may also enable us to understand thresholds, lags and sequences in the process by which developmental grand strategies and nuclear postures become linked.
Because international institutions bankroll free-trade coalitions, they are a great source of strength for such coalitions, as repositories of side-payment "currency." At the same time, they constitute a potential Achilles heel, a symbol of curtailed sovereignty. Thus, these institutions must calibrate their performance to enable cooperative coalitions to mobilize societal resources in support of nuclear regimes. Imposing heavy burdens on such coalitions may result in their "involuntary defection,"55/ or in their inability to deliver because of low prospects for domestic ratification. Understanding the impact of international processes on the strength of domestic coalitions is not equivalent to reducing the politics of these countries to external forces. As the international political economy literature suggests, different coalitions have chosen contrasting grand strategies of industrialization (integrative or inward-looking) under similar international circumstances.
Finally, economic liberalization appears to require democratization if it is to be sustained over the long term. In that sense, it may well be that many regional partners negotiating nuclear regimes, now and in the future, are and will be democratic. Yet, it could still be that both democracy and nuclear cooperation are outcomes of economic liberalism. Exploring further the extent to which political freedom will be necessary or sufficient for the emergence and maintenance of regional nuclear regimes is a compelling task for a social science theory sensitive to the construction of a more peaceful global order.
NOTES:
1. Regimes involve mutual policy adjustments through a joint process of coordination and collaboration leading to the establishment of binding principles, rules and decision-making procedures.
2. I am aggregating under the "nationalist" rubric an eclectic group that often colludes in challenging different aspects of liberalizing agendas. Not all elements are present everywhere, and their relative strength varies across states and regions. The confessional category includes radical ethnic or religious groups that are commonly labelled "fundamentalist." Because of some uneasiness with this last term -- among some scholars of Islam, for instance -- I use the terms radical or extreme confessionalism instead.
3. "Fence-sitters" are undecided states reluctant to commit themselves fully and effectively to a denuclearizing regime (it is important to differentiate between a formal commitment, such as Iraq's ratification of the NPT, and an effective one). Such states can wait to make the ultimate declaratory political stand while sitting on various types of fences (some with basements), holding different levels of nuclear capabilities. The term "fence-sitting" thus: (1) refers to effective international political postures, not military status; (2) can accommodate an array of countries that are often attributed different ranges of capabilities, intentions and formal commitments; and (3) seems preferable to an older term -- "nth countries" -- which often evokes the image of a compulsive, irrevocable march towards the emergence of the next "n." See Etel Solingen, "The Domestic Sources of Nuclear Postures: `Fence-sitting' in the Post-Cold War Era," IGCC Policy Paper No. 8 (University of California, Institute on Global Conflict and Cooperation, San Diego, 1994).
4. Of course, competition in the realm of security explains almost singlehandedly the decisions of the original five nuclear weapons states in the decade following World War II. The focus in this article is, however, on second-tier states, who have weighed their nuclear postures against a different "world-time," characterized by a highly integrated global economy and an integrating multilateral institutional foundation.
5. The lack of a rigorous examination of the domestic sources of nuclear postures among fence-sitters is particularly puzzling in light of the lessons from the U.S.-Soviet experience, where domestic processes acquired paramount importance in explaining arms control negotiations and eventual steps toward dramatic, if incomplete, nuclear reductions. Yet, the nonproliferation literature has largely resisted analytical inroads such as those that Matthew Evangelista and Jack Snyder applied to the study of major powers. See Matthew Evangelista, Innovation and the Arms Race: How the United States and the Soviet Union Develop New Military Technologies (Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press, 1988); Jack Snyder, Myths of Empire: Domestic Politics and International Ambition (Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press, 1991). There is also the tendency to ignore the links between security and trade strategies discussed, for example, in Richard Rosecrance, The Rise of the Trading State (New York: Basic Books, 1986).
6. This argument might explain the development of an Israeli nuclear deterrent. However, a 1986 public opinion poll found two-thirds of the Israeli public opposing the use of nuclear weapons under any circumstances. Asher Arian, Ilan Talmud and Tamar Hermann, National Security and Public Opinion in Israel (Boulder, Colorado: Westview, 1988), p. 96. Similarly, democratic South Korea does not appear to be responding to North Korean nuclear behavior with a nuclear deterrent of its own.
7. In fact, authoritarian rulers may enter an agreement and defect soon after, as Saddam Hussein's recanting of his earlier acceptance of some cease-fire stipulations demonstrates.
8. Timothy D. Sisk, Islam and Democracy (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Institute of Peace, 1992).
9. Of first-tier nuclear powers, it might be argued that the three democracies in that group (the United States, France and Britain) "went nuclear" to confront bitter non-democratic rivals (fascism first, communism later).
10. See Peter Gourevitch, "The Second Image Reversed: The International Sources of Domestic Politics," International Organization, Vol. 32, No. 4 (Autumn 1978), pp. 881-911.
11. Initially, the United States applied these measures unilaterally, particularly through the Symington amendment (1976) and the U.S. Non-proliferation Act (1979). Multilateral mechanisms soon followed, such as the Nuclear Suppliers Group, organized in 1977, now including more than 27 states.
12. Structural adjustment is "a set of measures designed to make the economy competitive." It often includes currency devaluation, deficit reduction, de-indexing of wages, reduction in consumer subsidies, price deregulation, and tariff reductions. See Adam Przeworski, Democracy and the Market: Political and Economic Reforms in Eastern Europe and Latin America (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1991), p. 144; Joan Nelson, Fragile Coalitions: The Politics of Economic Adjustment (New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction, 1989).
13. Rent-seeking refers to the unproductive economic activities of groups that seek transfers of wealth under the aegis of the state. See J.M. Buchanan, R.D. Tollison and C. Tullock, eds., Toward a Theory of the Rent-Seeking Society (College Station: Texas A & M University Press, 1980), p. 4. Debunking the conventional wisdom that nuclear weapons are universally cheap, see Steven E. Miller, "The Case Against a Ukrainian Nuclear Deterrent," Foreign Affairs, Vol. 72, No. 3 (Summer 1993), pp. 67-80. A nuclear weapons program was expected to require three-fourths of the entire outlay of India's proposed Fourth Five-Year Plan. See Mitchell Reiss, Without the Bomb (New York: Columbia University Press, 1988), p. 213.
14. Valeriana Kallab and Richard E. Feinberg, eds., Fragile Coalitions: The Politics of Economic Adjustment (New Brunswick, New Jersey: Transaction, 1989); and Robert R. Kaufman, "Domestic Determinants of Stabilization and Adjustment Choices," in Bruce M. Russett, Harvey Starr and Richard Stoll, eds., Choices in World Politics: Sovereignty and Interdependence (New York: W.H. Freeman, 1989), pp. 261-282; also, Yahya M. Sadowski, Scuds or Butter? The Political Economy of Arms Control in the Middle East (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1993), p. 32.
15. Snyder, Myths of Empire, p. 17. On chauvinist mythmaking as a hallmark of nationalism, see Stephen Van Evera, "Hypotheses on Nationalism and War," International Security, Vol. 18, No. 4 (Spring 1994), pp. 5-39.
16. Political institutions affect when and how certain coalitions of interests can prevail. See, for example, Peter A. Gourevitch, Politics in Hard Times: Comparative Responses to International Economic Crises (Ithaca, New York: Cornell University Press, 1986). There is considerable variation in the way in which the preferences of different coalitions are aggregated. For instance, incipient democratization and electoral trial-runs provided new opportunities for nationalist-confessional coalitions in the Middle East. These opportunities were quickly shut down where the military perceived them to weaken its institutional viability and strength, as in Algeria in 1991. In Israel, proportional representation has precluded the emergence of a single dominant coalition. Understanding the domestic determinants of different coalitions' success in gaining or maintaining power is an important question in itself, but not a task that can be undertaken here.
17. For a well-argued case on the centrality of regime survival and on the incompleteness (at best) and incorrectness (at worst) of the external-security interpretation of North Korea's behavior, see James Cotton, "North Korea's Nuclear Ambitions," in Asia's International Role in the Post-Cold War Era, Adelphi Paper No. 275, Part I (London: IISS, 1993), pp. 94-106. On the struggle between moderates and hard-liners in North Korea, see Selig S. Harrison, "Three Myths May Foil Progress," The New York Times, June 24, 1994, p. A11; also, Michael J. Mazarr, "Lessons of the North Korean Crisis," Arms Control Today, July/August 1993, p. 9.
18. Reiss, Without the Bomb, pp. 204-46. On how external crises strengthened the Congress party ruling coalition and the opposition to denuclearization, see Ashok Kapur, "Nuclear Scientists and the State: The Nehru and Post-Nehru Years," in Etel Solingen, ed., Scientists and the State: Domestic Structures and the International Context (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1994).
19. India and Pakistan signed an agreement in late 1988 not to attack each other's nuclear facilities. On Benazir Bhutto's effort to stop weapons-grade uranium production, see David Albright, "India and Pakistan's Nuclear Arms Race: Out of the Closet but not in the Street," Arms Control Today, June 1993, p. 15. On Rajiv Gandhi's liberalizing agenda and its unraveling, see Atul Kohli, "The Politics of Economic Liberalization in India," in Ezra N. Suleiman and John Waterbury, eds., The Political Economy of Public Sector Reform and Privatization (Boulder, Colorado: Westview, 1991), pp. 364-88.
20. PPNN Newsbrief (University of Southampton: Programme for Promoting Nuclear Non-Proliferation -- PPNN), Winter 1991-92, p. 3. On pressures from the opposition to prevent Rao from making concessions in the nuclear field, see John F. Burns, "India Resists Plan to Curb Nuclear Arms," The New York Times, May 15, 1994, p. 8.
21. Ann E. Mayer, "The Fundamentalist Impact on Law, Politics, and Constitutions in Iran, Pakistan, and the Sudan," in Marty and Appleby, Fundamentalisms and the State (Chicago, Illinois: University of Chicago Press, 1993), p. 131. In July 1991, Pakistan expressed interest in signing the NPT unilaterally (without India doing so) if the United States would reinstate aid cut off under the Pressler Amendment. Eye on Supply (Monterey Institute of International Studies), No. 6 (Spring 1992), p. 11.
22. Not necessarily advocates of an open deterrent, the militaries in India and Pakistan surely benefit from an ambiguous posture that is more likely to ensure continued budgetary support than is a program of denuclearization. On support of dual-use technologies within the scientific-industrial complex, see Kapur, ""Nuclear Scientists and the State," p. 214.
23. Edward A. Gargan, "Bhutto Standing by Nuclear Program," The New York Times, October 21, 1993, p. A9.
24. The New York Times, January 24, 1993. On BJP leader Lai Krishna Advani's statement that India will go nuclear when BJP comes to power, see PPNN Newsbrief, Second Quarter 1993, p. 14. On the historical support of nuclear weapons by the ultranationalist Jana Sangh Party and the People's Socialist Party, see Reiss, Without the Bomb, p. 323.
25. On the party's political basis, see Mumtaz Ahmad, "Islamic Fundamentalism in South Asia: The Jamaat-i-Islami and the Tablighi Jamaat of South Asia," in Martin E. Marty and R. Scott Appleby, eds., Fundamentalisms Observed (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1991), pp. 457-530.
26. Edward A. Gargan, "A Talk with Bhutto: Is Her Sure Touch Slipping?" The New York Times, June 19, 1993. In February 1992, Foreign Minister Shahryar Khan announced that Pakistan had the components to assemble such a weapon. John J. Schulz, "Riding the Nuclear Tiger: The Search for Security in South Asia," Arms Control Today, June 1993, p. 5. On Benazir Bhutto's statement that the military had kept her in the dark with respect to the nuclear program, see "N-controversy," The Nation, p. 2.
27. Israel has not signed the NPT but has supported the idea of a NWFZ at the UN, particularly since 1980. On this and other aspects of Israel's nuclear postures, see Solingen, "The Domestic Sources."
28. Sadowski, Scuds or Butter? p. 41. In 1974, Egypt was also ready to accept full-scope safeguards following the U.S. proposal to supply nuclear reactors to Egypt and Israel. Pro-Soviet Nasserites like Ali Sabri, Ahmed Sidki and Hasnein Haikal continued advocating nuclear weapons. See Amos Perlmutter, Michael Handel and Uri Bar-Joseph, Two Minutes Over Baghdad (London: Vallentine, Mitchell, 1982), p. 33; Fuad Jabber, Israel and Nuclear Weapons (London: IISS/Chatto and Windus, 1971), p. 141.
29. Binder, Islamic Liberalism, (Chicago, Illinois: University of Chicago Press, 1988), pp. 357-358; Springborg, Mubarak's Egypt (Boulder, Colorado: Westview Press, 1959), pp. 63-69.
30. On nuclear weapons in the Muslim world as redemptive anti-colonial tools, see Ali Mazrui, "The Political Culture of War and Nuclear Proliferation: A Third World Perspective," in Hugh C. Dyer and Leon Mangasarian, eds., The Study of International Relations (London: Macmillan, 1989). See also Pervez Hoodbhoy, "Myth-Building: The `Islamic' Bomb," The Bulletin of the Atomic Scientists, June 1993, pp. 42-49.
31. See Mary-Jane Deeb, "Militant Islam and the Politics of Redemption," Annals, American Academy of Political and Social Sciences, Vol. 524 (November 1992), pp. 52-65. On the lack of evidence that Islamic economics has made Muslim economies more just, equal, productive or innovative, see Timur Kuran, "Fundamentalist Economics and The Economic Roots of Fundamentalism: Policy Prescriptions for a Liberal Society," in Martin E. Marty and R. Scott Appleby, eds., Fundamentalisms and Public Policy (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, forthcoming 1995).
32. Hazem Beblawi and Giacomo Luciani, Nation, State and Integration in the Arab World, Vol. 2: The Rentier State (London: Croom Helm, 1987).
33. Leon T. Hadar, "What Green Peril?" Foreign Affairs, Vol. 27, No. 2 (Spring 1993), pp. 27-42; Sisk, Islam and Democracy, p. 35; Kuran, "Fundamentalist Economics." Hassan Salame argues that, in practice, moderates and militants alike play a political game that mutually reinforces their bargaining power. See Salame, "Islam and the West," Foreign Policy, Vol. 90 (Spring 1993), pp. 22-37; and G. Hossein Razi, "Legitimacy, Religion, and Nationalism in the Middle East," American Political Science Review, Vol. 84, No. 1 (March 1990), pp. 69-92.
34. PPNN Newsbrief (Winter 1992), p. 15; Hoodbhoy, "Myth-Building," p. 43.
35. Sadowski, Scuds or Butter? p. 63; The New York Times, January 31, 1993, p. 6.
36. Phebe Marr, The Modern History of Iraq (Boulder, Colorado: Westview, 1985); and Yousef A. Ahmad, "The Dialectics of Domestic Environment and Role Performance: The Foreign Policy of Iraq," in Baghat Korany and Ali E. Hillal Dessouki, eds., The Foreign Policy of Arab States (Boulder, Colorado: Westview, 1991), pp. 186-215.
37. Robert E. Harkavy, Spectre of a Middle Eastern Holocaust: The Strategic and Diplomatic Implications of the Israeli Nuclear Weapons Program, University of Denver Graduate School of International Studies, Monograph Series in World Affairs, Vol. 14, Book 4 (1977); Shai Feldman, Israeli Nuclear Deterrence (New York: Columbia University Press, 1982); Louis Rene Beres, ed., Security or Armageddon (Lexington, Massachusetts: Lexington Books, 1986); Shlomo Aronson, The Politics and Strategy of Nuclear Weapons in the Middle East (Albany: State University of New York Press, 1992); also Solingen, "The Domestic Sources of Regimes"; Naomi Chazan, "The Domestic Foundations of Israeli Foreign Policy," in Judith Kipper and Harold H. Saunders, eds., The Middle East in Global Perspective (Boulder, Colorado: Westview, 1991), pp. 82-126.
38. Barnett, Confronting the Costs of War (Princeton, New Jersey: Princeton University Press, 1993), p. 233.
39. Ephraim Inbar, "Israel and Nuclear Weapons since October 1973," in Beres, Security or Armageddon, pp. 61-68; Simha Flaphan, "Nuclear Power in the Middle East," New Outlook, July 1974, pp. 46-54. The Committee for Denuclearization of the Middle East was headed by a prominent Knesset member from Labor (Mapai), Eliezer Livne, and had good access to prominent Labor figures. Avner Cohen, "Nuclear Weapons, Opacity, and Israeli Democracy," in Avner Yaniv, ed., National Security and Democracy in Israel (Boulder, Colorado: Lynne Rienner, 1993), pp. 205-07 and p. 224.
40. Inbar, "Israel and Nuclear Weapons," p. 64. Moshe Dayan later joined a Likud government.
41. Yehoshafat Harkabi, Israel's Fateful Hour (New York: Harper & Row, 1988); Ephraim Inbar, War and Peace in Israeli Politics (Boulder, Colorado: Lynne Rienner, 1991), p. 105. On the proclivity of this public to regard the threat of war as much more probable than peace, see A. Arian, I. Talmud and T. Hermann, National Security and Public Opinion in Israel (Boulder, Colorado: Westview, 1988), p. 72.
42. Perlmutter, Two Minutes, pp. 80-81; and Inbar, War and Peace, p. 105. The Chief of Staff at the time was Rafael Eitan, who went on to create a new political party with high ideological affinity to Likud.
43. As a reward for the Rabin government's more flexible positions in the Middle East peace talks, even prior to September 1993, the United States approved $10 billion in loan guarantees for investments in infrastructure and jobs, a program that may help solidify Labor's position as the core of future coalitions. Likud had chosen to retain an intractable position in the peace negotiations at the expense of economic gains. The issue of the loan guarantees reaffirms the need to transcend neorealist interpretations of state behavior. Moreover, Labor's flexible positions were far from externally imposed; the loan approval was a windfall for a policy that Labor supported anyway.
44. Quoted in Eric Silver, Financial Times, December 7, 1992.
45. Mario Mariscotti, El Secreto Atomico de Huemul (Buenos Aires: Sudamericana-Planeta, 1987).
46. Regina L. de Morel, Ciencia e Estado: A politica cientifica no Brasil (Sao Paulo: T.A. Queiroz, 1979). On the political economy of the nuclear sector in Brazil and Argentina, see Etel Solingen, Industrial Policy, Technology, and International Bargaining: Designing Nuclear Industries in Argentina and Brazil (Stanford: Stanford University Press, forthcoming 1995).
47. Daniel Poneman, "Nuclear Proliferation Prospects for Argentina," Orbis, Vol. 27, No. 4 (Winter 1984), pp. 853-880. On the evolution of these postures, see John R. Redick, "Argentina- Brazil Nuclear Non-Proliferation Initiatives," PPNN, No. 3 (January 1994).
48. Ruth Stanley, "Cooperation and Control: The New Approach to Nuclear Non-proliferation in Argentina and Brazil," Arms Control, Vol. 13, No. 2 (September 1992), pp. 191-213.
49. This shift included, for instance, Argentine naval participation in the Gulf War and a severance of membership in the Nonaligned Movement. Roberto Russell, ed., La politica exterior Argentina en el nuevo orden mundial (Buenos Aires: Facultad Latinoamericana de Ciencias Sociales, 1992).
50. On how ensuring a favorable economic and investment climate underpinned the agreement, see Stanley, "Cooperation," p. 207.
51. Redick, "Argentina-Brazil," p. 4.
52. Scott Tollefson, Memorandum (Monterey, California: Naval Postgraduate School, 1992); and Redick, "Argentina-Brazil," pp. 1-3.
53. Miles Kahler, "International Financial Institutions and the Politics of Adjustment," in Kallab and Feinberg, Fragile Coalitions; Kaufman, "Domestic Determinants."
54. On the social costs of economic adjustment, see Joan M. Nelson, "Poverty, Equity, and the Politics of Adjustment," in Haggard and Kaufman, The Politics, pp. 221-69. On the negative effects of neoliberal economic reform on democratic institutions, see Adam Przeworski, "The Neoliberal Fallacy," Journal of Democracy, Vol. 3, No. 3 (July 1992), pp. 45-59. On economic decline as leading to the rise of militant Islam, see Deeb, "Militant Islam," p. 53.
55. The term is Robert D. Putnam's in "Diplomacy and Domestic Politics," International Organization, Vol. 42, No. 3 (Summer 1988), pp. 427-459. NNNN
File Identification: 02/13/95, FAR108
Product Name: Global Issues in Transition, Issue No 12
Product Code: GL
Keywords: NUCLEAR WEAPONS; POLITICAL ECONOMY; NUCLEAR NON-PROLIFERATION; KOREA (SOUTH)/Defense & Military; KOREA (NORTH)/Defense & Military; SOUTH ASIA/Defense & Military; MIDDLE EAST/Defense & Military; ARGENTINA/Defense & Military; BR
Document Type: REP
Thematic Codes: 1AC
Target Areas: AF; AR; EA; EU; NE
PDQ Text Link: 379396